(This is Part 2 in a series of blogs I am doing entitled “Why It Doesn’t Make Economic Sense to Run Education like a Business.”)
We’ve all been students, so we recognize this scenario: a professor announces that the next class will be cancelled. Our reaction?
Of course, if we students are really “customers” and education is a “product,” then we are just pretty stupid consumers. Think about it. If we had purchased an 8-day package vacation in Aruba and the travel agent called us up on the beach and told us that one day of the vacation had been cancelled and we would have to fly back early, we would not be happy campers. Or sun-bathers, as it were.
Then why are we so happy to miss a day of education, especially when higher education is so expensive?
Education is a different animal.
Students don’t want to get their money’s worth. Barlow’s Law seems so common-sensically obvious (at least in American culture) that I probably ought to call it Barlow’s axiom, which would make it a self-evident truth.
Teachers know that they can please their students by giving them less instruction or less demanding education. If a professor cuts an assignment, reduces reading, or eases up in any way, many students are happy. Many students will try to sign up for easy professors. Many figure out ways to get a decent grade with the smallest amount of work. Many cheat. If we are let out of class early, we are happy. Meanwhile, if extra reading and writing is required, we “customers” will complain and protest that the professor is being unfair.
Imagine striking a deal for a new Lexus and getting excited when the dealer says he will have to cut out the heated seats or the air conditioning. Imagine complaining and protesting that the dealer is being unfair if he throws in a sun roof at no extra cost.
According to Adam Smith, society benefits under capitalism because self-interest leads businesses to produce better and cheaper products which is what customers, in their self-interest, want. The problem is that self-interest is a complicated thing. Yes, we know it is in our self-interest to get a good education. But we also have immediate self-interests that run counter to the long-term habits required to obtain a good education: we would rather play video games or hang with friends or eat nachos or check Facebook or sleep than study. A truly stupid show on Comedy Central suddenly becomes absolutely fascinating when we have a paper to write. Socialized from childhood as a consumer (see “Trix: cereal”), what’s a “customer” to do?
Now, it is true that there are students who sincerely want the very best that an academic course can give them. Many do not want easy professors or classes where they learn little. In fact, most of us have probably gone back and forth between desiring a good, challenging class and wishing it were cancelled. Usually, though, true academic desires and virtues are cultivated over time from parents or a great teacher along the way, but not from our economic system. The desires for a challenging class stem from impulses opposite of those intensified by consumerism, such as immediate gratification, entertainment, comfort and self-indulgence.
You might point out that the economic desire for a well-paying job motivates many students to do well. True, but I would question whether this is really the best kind of education one can get. In fact, not all ambitious, highly motivated students deeply desire the best education they can get. An undefinable number of hard-working, ambitious students highly desire the status or connections or economic opportunities that an education can give them, as opposed to the education itself. In other words, many are more interested in a diploma from a prestigious institution or good grades than they are in what a given course will actually teach them. And they will pay a lot of money for this. A few years ago, a college in Pennsylvania did nothing but increase its tuition by a significant amount (several thousands of dollars) under the theory that students would perceive the school to have more prestige with an increased price. Their applications from high-achieving students went up.
That points to another unsettling possibility: treating students as customers may actually be increasing the cost of higher education. In their competition for “customers,” colleges feel the pressure to build single-person dorm rooms, lavish student centers, hip dining halls, and numerous support services to attract students. Sometimes I ask non-athletes if they would be willing to have our college cut all intercollegiate athletics, if it would save them $1500/year on their tuition. Most would not want to change – they would rather pay more to have athletics on campus, even if they are not competing themselves. Socialized from childhood as consumers, (see “Trix: cereal”), students want a particular lifestyle in college.
When we treat education as a consumer item, we end up with an inferior product at a higher price. This seems to be what “customers” want.
So, does it really make economic sense to run education on a business model?